
March 2015 73
time and thinking almost exclusively over the past few years. It
is the reason why I am happy to confess to the sin that is appor-
tioned to me by radical critics of my ‘Menshevik’ stand on the
Eurozone: the sin of choosing not to propose radical political
programs that seek to exploit the Euro Crisis as an opportu-
nity to overthrow European capitalism, to dismantle the awful
Eurozone, and to undermine the European Union of the cartels
and the bankrupt bankers.
Yes, I would love to put forward such a radical agenda. But,
no, I am not prepared to commit the same error twice. What
good did we achieve in Britain in the early 1980s by promot-
ing an agenda of socialist change that British society scorned
while falling headlong into Mrs Thatcher’s neo-liberal trap?
Precisely none. What good will it do today to call for a dis-
mantling of the Eurozone, of the European Union itself, when
European capitalism is doing its utmost to undermine the
Eurozone, the European Union, indeed itself?
When I moved to Australia in 1988, unbeknownst to me,
I was recruited by the right wing of the Sydney University
Economics Department in order to keep out of the Faculty
another candidate whose former supervisor was thought
of (quite rightly!) as a dangerous Marxist. Later I moved to
Greece where I (foolishly) became, quite officially, an advisor
of George Papandreou – the man whose government was to
mediate Greece’s passage to Hell a few years later. Even though
I had resigned as Mr Papandreou’s adviser early in 2006, and
turned into his government’s staunchest critic during his mis-
handling of the post-2009 Greek implosion, my interventions
in the public debate on Greece and Europe (e.g. the Modest
Proposal for Resolving the Euro Crisis, that I co-authored and
have been campaigning in favour of) does not have a whiff of
Marxism in it.
In view of this long path through academia and the policy
debates on Europe, one may be puzzled to hear me come out
of the proverbial closet as a Marxist. Such pronouncements
do not come naturally to me. I wish I could avoid hetero-def-
initions (i.e. being defined by someone else’s worldview and
method). Marxist, Hegelian, Keynesian, Humean, I have a nat-
ural tendency to say that I am none of these things; that I have
spent my days trying to become Francis Bacon’s bee: a crea-
ture that samples the nectar of a million flowers and turns it,
in its gut, into something new, something of one’s own, some-
thing that owes much to every single bloom but is defined by
no single flower.
Alas, this would be untrue and no fit way to begin a…
confession.
In truth, Karl Marx was responsible for framing my perspec-
tive of the world we live in, from my childhood to this day. It
is not something that I volunteer to talk about in ‘polite soci-
ety’ much these days because the very mention of the M-word
switches audiences off. But I never deny it either. In fact, after
a few years of addressing audiences with which I do not share
an ideological milieu, a need has crept up on me recently to talk
candidly about Marx’s imprint on my thinking.
To explain why, while an unapologetic Marxist, I think it is
important to resist him passionately in a variety of ways. To
be, in other words, erratic in one’s Marxism.
If my whole academic career largely ignored Marx, and my
current policy recommendations are impossible to describe
as Marxist, why bring up my Marxism now? The answer is
simple: Even my non-Marxist economics was guided by a
mindset influenced heavily by Marx. A radical social theorist
can challenge the economics mainstream in two different
ways, I always thought. One way is by means of immanent crit-
icism. To accept the mainstream’s axioms and then expose
its internal contradictions. To say: “I shall not contest your
assumptions but here is why your own conclusions do not logi-
cally flow on from them.”
This was, indeed, Marx’s method of undermining British
political economics. He accepted every axiom by Adam Smith
and David Ricardo in order to demonstrate that, in the con-
text of their assumptions, capitalism was a contradictory
system. The second avenue that a radical theorist can pursue
is, of course, the construction of alternative theories to those
of the Establishment, hoping that they will be taken seriously
(which is what later 20th Century Marxist economists have
been doing).
My view on this dilemma has always been that the powers-
that-be are never perturbed by theories that embark from
assumptions different to their own. No established economist
will even pay attention to a Marxist or neo-Ricardian model
these days. The only thing that can destabilise and genuinely
challenge mainstream, neoclassical economists is the demon-
stration of the internal inconsistency of their own models. It
was for this reason that, from the very beginning, I chose to
delve into the ‘guts’ of neoclassical theory and to spend next
to no energy trying to develop alternative, Marxist, models of
capitalism. My reasons, I submit, were quite… Marxist.
I carried on teaching, at the University of Athens, quaint
(and admittedly vulgar bourgeois) subjects like Game Theory
and Microeconomics to a large number of Greek undergrad-
uates, who (unlike our brave and extremely well informed
graduate students) remained touchingly oblivious to the catas-
trophe about to befall them.
Back in 2002, well before the Global Crisis erupted, Joseph
Halevi and I tried to sound a warning – but we failed to make
an impact. Even though in 2006 I did my best to warn Greek
society, and anyone who would listen, of the impending disas-
ter, I shamefully remained part of Athens’ and Europe’s ‘polite
society’, not once taking to the streets.
When the Global Crisis erupted in 2008, and soon engulfed
the Eurozone, I began writing articles and making frantic
appearances in established and less mainstream media alike,
promoting a fundamentally bourgeois agenda for saving
capitalism from itself! When the going got really tough, at a
personal level, in Greece, I migrated to the USA and took up
an appointment at the University of Texas.
To this day, I am struggling to impress the powers-that-be
that they must urgently adopt specific bold policy recommen-
dations in order to prevent an inevitable crisis from crushing
capitalism. In summary, not one of my academic publications
can be thought of as explicitly Marxist, while my energies are
channeled into preventing capitalism’s collapse.
Nonetheless, all along, from my student days in Britain to
this very day, the only way I could make sense of the world we
live in is through the methodological ‘eyes’ of Karl Marx. In
itself, this ‘fact’ renders me a theoretical Marxist.
Moreover, I feel Marxism in my bones every time I am
engaged in any form of intellectual pursuit: from discuss-
ing the Arab Spring to debating the intricacies of Art with my
artist partner.
Furthermore, a democratic, libertarian, socialist future is
the only future that I would be willing to fight for. A most pecu-
liar Marxist no doubt, but a Marxist nevertheless. •
Radicals
should work
toward
minimising the
human toil,
reinforcing
Europe’s
public
institutions
and, therefore,
buying time
and space
in which to
develop a
genuinely
humanist
alternative
“