VILLAGEAugust/September 
H
OUSING in Ireland raises ethical
issue s, thou gh for histor ic al rea sons
we tend to see them almost exclu-
sively as practical (or ‘economic’) ones.
There is no other broad area of Irish soci-
ety where public trust in institutions has
been more corroded. Housing has been
central to the collapse in Ireland’s State and
personalnances and in respect for the pub-
lic interest (such as it ever existed).
Its supply, distributionnancing and prof-
its are at the heart of fairness in this country.
Of course, most people in Ireland have no
clear views on ethics or the absence of ethics
in our housing system. Indeed our housing
policies have generally been more about
extending property ownership, boosting
the construction industry, increasing public
spending (in counter and pro-cyclical styles),
facilitating lending and rewarding or provid-
ing for particular groups in society.
In , an American academic, based at
the Institute of Public Administration, stud-
ied the Irish housing system and concluded
that it was the most heavily subsidised in the
world. If he returned today and made simi-
lar investigations in relation to the housing
tax reliefs over the past  years, absence
of tax on betterment and development, rent
and mortgage supports, and the colossal
State bailout of loans on development land,
POLITICS
Also in this section:
Piketty Special: Gurdgiev 30
Lone parents 33
Piketty Special: Buckley 34
Basic income 38
Living wage 39
Revolution 40
Abortion 43
Housing ownership, supply, distribution, financing, subsidisation, profit,
taxation, planning, quality, standards, regulation and economics determine a
lot about Irish society. By Padraic Kenna
Ethics not immutable
economics’ should drive
housing policy
money wins
August/September VILLAGE
he would probably be shocked. Calculating
how much of the Irish State € billion bail-
out bill is related to residential development
land would give us some idea of the extent of
these market subsidies. Clearly, nobody is
doing that kind of economic research these
days.
However, these market subsidies to
lenders, developers and landowners are
politically acceptable, although rarely
discussed.
When house prices reach a level at which
significant numbers of new households are
unable to afford homeownership or even
home rental, governments are faced with
a dilemma, described by Pfretzschner in
:
“Either [a government] can take the steps
to raise the level of wages, pensions and
benefits sufficiently so that each family
can afford to pay an economic rent, or it
can take steps to provide the shelter, or to
assure its provision, and absorb the loss
itself, meaning that the burden of the loss
is passed along in the form of higher tax-
ation and/or rates to the rest of society.
Of course, today, states have developed
many effective instruments to direct the
housing system, through planning, taxes,
regulation etc, although in Ireland many of
them are only marginally acceptable even
in the wake of the Irish housing market
fiasco.
As lon g ago a s , Hen ry Ge orge pointed
out that as the productive output of coun-
tries increased, such as in Ireland during
the past years, much of the increased
wages and salaries can get swallowed up in
housing costs. The huge increase in produc-
tive power does not result in increased real
standards of living, but rather in an increase
in the value of land. Indeed, the increase in
land and housing costs prevents increasingly
productive citizens from enjoying ethical
increases in living standards and developing
their full potential. In Ireland, the long com-
mute (so as to afford a decent-sized home)
and the absence of quality family time, as
a result of expensive urban housing, is well
established as a legend of our Celtic Tiger
housing bubble.
What is remarkable is that building costs
have not increased that much at all, yet
access to a decent home costs more and
more in terms of multiples of annual earn-
ings. Here, the hidden price of land and the
profits of the developer are concealed.
Henry George in ‘Progress and Poverty
() states thatall the advantages gained
by the march of progress go to the owners
of land. A house and the land on which it
stands are treated as property by the law, –
yet in nature they differ widely. The “one
is produced by human labour” and the other
is part of nature.
Lawyers look on the private ownership of
land as the foundation of society. Yet, most
people believe that it is unethical that owners
of land should benefit from publicly funded
and organised improvements in its location,
connection to services, planning and zoning.
Peoples homes and front gardens cannot be
regarded as the same as development land.
Indeed, the Kenny Report in the s
suggested that local authorities be given
the power to designate land required for
development and the right to acquire this
land at a price  per cent above its value
in its existing use. The All-Party Oireachtas
Committee on the Constitution Ninth Report
on Private Property () called for a
“new mindset” in how we look at develop-
ment land in Ireland. It suggested that the
community should benefit from the better-
ment” of land created by zoning, planning,
infrastructure connections etc. A planning-
gain levy was mooted in the s. This has
now been enacted, with surprisingly little
public awareness, in the NAMA Act ,
which introduced a “windfall tax” on dis-
posals of development land, to the extent
to which they are attributable to rezoning.
Capital Gains Tax is exacted at a special rate
of %. The danger in Ireland is that this
will be insidiously removed sometime soon
on grounds that it might raise prices. This
particular issue should be an ethical not a
practical one.
A recurrent property tax on all land
zoned for development where the land was
not being developed was proposed by the
Commission on Taxation in .
The idea of a site value tax (SVT) on land
(including where homes have already been
built) is to capture the underlying value of
developed land. In general, the value of a site
derives from its location and accessibility
to publicly funded or subsidised services,
a policy
that
didn’t
work
VILLAGEAugust/September 
is that in many cases it is of poor quality,
badly managed and tends to create a third-
class citizenship.
This third-class citizenship is reinforced
for example by the lack of a complaints or
dispute-resolution process (unlike the sit-
uation with private-rented housing); the
absence of any enforcement (or even inspec-
tion) process for violations of housing
standards; and the absence of any remedies
for tenants who are treated unfairly.
There have been regulations on stand-
ards in rented housing since .However,
while these apply to local-authority housing,
the local authority itself is the inspection
and enforcement body. Needless to say there
have been no enforcement actions in rela-
tion to such accommodation. We know that
estates in Dublins Dolphin’s Barn and in
Limerick endure unacceptable conditions,
yet tenants have no way of enforcing stand-
ards. Private-renting tenants can appeal
to the Private Rented Tenancies Board
about any dispute with a landlord, but local
authority tenants have no such facility and
must rely on the Ombudsman – who has no
enforcement powers.
Further disenfranchisement flows from
the fact that Ireland is unique in Europe in
lacking a representative organisation of ten-
ants in either private or social sectors. Some
, household local authority tenant
households and , private renting
households have no representative organ-
isation to enable them to have a say in the
making of laws and policies which affect
them. These decisions and laws have an
overwhelming impact on the lifetime oppor-
tunities of themselves or their children. In
Ireland, citizenship and property ownership
are siblings, still close friends while non-
owners are still outsiders (and there are no
plans anywhere to change this).
Our housing and landowning system is out
of step with our constitution. Article ..
states that All citizens shall, as human per-
sons, be held equal before the law. While
there may be formal equality in the courts,
there is substantial and real inequality in
society. Housing consumers are not equal
to developers. Tenants, especially those in
local authority housing, do not even have the
opportunity to raise such issues.
In housing debates today, we rarely hear
of new paradigms of thought and action.
Droning about the immutable “iron laws
of housing markets continues to constitute
a starting point for most commentators.
The Great Recession provided an opportu-
nity for a rethink centring on the truth that
so long as housing is unethical, society will
remain unfair.
facilities and utilities”. No SVT has been
introduced in Ireland, though it was prom-
ised in the programme for government.
Whereas a value-based property tax like the
one the coalition in the end pursued has the
ethical purpose of spreading wealth, a site
value tax serves the practical end of promot-
ing economic land use. Indeed the economic
imperative is so fine that it becomes an ethi-
cal purpose in its own right. The motivations
of ‘property’ and ‘site value’ taxes are sepa-
rate and Irish politicians should note that
one should not preclude the other.
Is it time to shift media and academic
commentary on housing from its simplistic
standard where reports on theiron laws of
supply and demand always accompany har-
rowing personal accounts of homelessness
and housing hardship, with nothing more
than superficial analysis of the system which
perpetuates both.
The experience of a decade ago show that
prices will rise to whatever purchasers can
afford (or borrow) even if building costs
barely increase. Is it good public policy to
allow housing (or land) to soak up all the
gains in productivity and output expressed
in the wages and salaries of society? Why
are development and infrastructure lev-
ies applied only to new homes? In the UK,
where increases are again pricing people
out of a home, some are suggesting using
graduated capital gains tax on primary res-
idences as a way of cooling prices – in the
public interest.
It is an ethical question to why we have a
housing system where , households
(or .%) were last year waiting for State
provision of housing.The Irish, largely pri-
vate, housing system does not serve all. Of
the , households some , were
employed. The waiting lists included ,
households on Rent Supplement. At least
, of households are on waiting lists
for more than  years.
Some , people accessed homeless-
ness service in  in Dublin, with 
families living in emergency housing in
hotels at the end of .
In the past few years horrendous abuses of
housing consumers have taken place. From
the tragicre safety breaches at Priory Hall
to the Pyrite scandal this is an ethical issue,
particularly as housing purchase takes up
almost all a person’s lifetime savings.
True, some new regulations have been
introduced this year, but they leave the
individual consumer in much the same posi-
tion. They must wait until a defect appears
in their home, then try and get a lawyer to
take a case against a builder of other pro-
fessional, ultimately fighting a lengthy and
expensive legal battle with an insurance
company possessing huge resources. We
need an ethical, accountable and effective
housing consumer agency which has real
enforcement powers rather than advising
people to ‘shop around’.
We also need a courageous State to
take a strong role inspecting all housing
developments, and not just the -%
contemplated by the so-called protocol with
the local authority Managers. Why not make
the local authority liable in neg-
ligence where a defect arises
which should have been obvi-
ous on inspection, as is the case
in the UK?
Most people nd it totally
unethical that a builder (who
may have built defective homes)
ca n w ind up a compa ny and avoid
any legal or personal liability
for any damage or ruin caused
to hapless house buyers. How
about personal bonds secured
properly to cover defects for
up to  years, to be held by a
State body – and not by a bank
or trade body?
What is an ethical profit for
a housing developer? Is a norm
of -% as much as society can
take or should we, for some
reason, allow a laissez-faire
approach?
At rst sight, the provision
of State housing through local
authorities seems to be an
activity of the highest ethical
standard. And indeed, over the past cen-
tury this has provided valuable and secure
homes for many people. Today, however,
many local authority housing estates have
become residualised – largely confined to
persons without employment and essentially
poor. This has followed successive policies
of council house sales. Since , there
has been a policy of “counteracting undue
segregation between people of
different social backgrounds.
While this might sound admira-
ble, it fails to mention different
economic backgrounds. The
result is a gloried, aspirational
but meaningless statement
which appears over and over in housing
and planning policies. A similar criticism
applies to the term “sustainable commu-
nities, which is now included in all State
housing policy documents, but which again
has no legally defined or enforceable sta-
tus. So while there are many high-minded
platitudes about State housing, the reality
POLITICS HOUSING
Dr Padraic Kenna is a
lecturer in the School
of Law, NUI Galway,
specialising in housing
law, rights and policy.
Whereas a
value-based
property tax
like the one the
coalition in the
end pursued
has the ethical
purpose of
spreading
wealth, an
SVT serves the
practical end
of promoting
economic land
use
August/September VILLAGE
some lone parents to stay in employment.
This cut comes on top of the other signi-
cant cuts to incomes and services that have
particularly targeted lone parents.
Lone parents who wish to take up edu-
cation or training opportunities will also
struggle due to the loss of the OFP. The pay-
ment can be claimed by those parenting
alone and undertaking education or training
courses, along with a
student maintenance
grant. Those who lose
the payment but who
wish to take up edu-
cat ion or tr ain ing w i ll
now have to claim the
Back to Education
Allowance. This can-
not be claimed at the
same time as a stu-
dent maintenance
grant. This fur-
ther disadvantages
lone parents on low
incomes with lim-
ited resources and
high levels of caring
responsibilities. It
will be too much for
many who will now
not take up education
and training oppor-
tunities as a result.
The loss of the OFP when the youngest
child turns seven years old will undermine
Government’s stated objective of support-
ing those in jobless households and assisting
families in low paid work. The development
of a system of quality childcare and after-
school care that is affordable and accessible
would have supported the Governments
objective of tackling poverty and jobless-
ness. Such a system would have
provided real support to all par-
ents, particularly those with low
earnings potential, to enter and
remain in the labour market.
Long term, passive recipiency of
a social welfare payment is in no one’s best
interests. However, penalising those lone
parents already in employment and mak-
ing it more difficult for those who might be
considering taking up employment, educa-
tion or training makes no sense. •
I
N July , over , recipients of
the One Parent Family Payment (OFP)
lost the payment. This was as a result
of the decision announced in Budget 
to restrict eligibility for the OFP to those
parenting alone whose youngest child is aged
seven or under.
Then-Minister for Social Protection, Joan
Burton TD, highlighted two reasons for
the decision. The first was the high rate of
poverty among lone parents in spite of con-
siderable expenditure on social welfare. The
second was the desire to support lone par-
ents getting employment, in order to tackle
poverty.
One-parent families have the highest rates
of poverty and deprivation of any family type
in Ireland with % at risk of poverty and
almost % experiencing basic depriva-
tion. The need to address poverty among
those parenting alone is clear. However, this
measure will actually make it more difficult
for them to take up employment, education
or training opportunities. This is because
they will no longer have access to the fea-
tures of the OFP which were designed with
the additional needs of those parenting alone
in mind.
In response to this concern Minister
Burton stated at the time that the change
would not be implemented before the intro-
duction of a safe, affordable and accessible
childcare system, similar to that available
in Scandinavian countries. There has been
some increased provision of childcare and
afterschool care places targeted at low
income families. However, provision still
falls far short of a Scandinavian system of
childcare. In spite of this, the changes to the
OFP have now proceeded as planned.
The loss of the OFP will be most keenly felt
by lone parents who are already in employ-
ment. A lone parent, by way of
example, who is earning €
per week net income and is
combining part-time employ-
ment with the OFP and Family
Income Supplement will have a
loss of income of around € per week. This
is in spite of an increase in the Family Income
Supplement payment, which, while vitally
important, is not enough to compensate fully
for the loss of the OFP. It is likely that this
loss of income will make it impossible for
A lone parent
who is earning
€200 per
week net and
is combining
part-time
employment
with the OFP
and Family
Income
Supplement will
lose €70 per
week
5,000 with youngest child
under seven lose payment.
By Caroline Fahey
Senseless penalising of lone
parent employees
LONE PARENTS POLITICS
Caroline Fahey is Social
Policy Development
Officer with Society of St
Vincent de Paul.
Now, how can we make
her life more difcult?

Loading

Back to Top