
2 6 April 2016
but for tax offences and contempt of the Tribu-
nal respectively. Lawlor died in a car crash in
Russia before any further charges could be laid
against him.
Criticisms based on a perceived lack of pros-
ecutions have also been levelled at the NSW
ICAC. To some extent this reflects a lack of
understanding that the responsibility for pros-
ecutions sits with the DPP, not the ICAC. More
fundamentally, though, it is not appropriate to
judge the success of anti-corruption agencies
solely, or even primarily, in terms of criminal
prosecutions. They are there to expose the
truth. It falls to others to serve up the just
deserts.
In recent days, the NSW Electoral Commis-
sion has decided that the Liberal Party of
Australia (NSW Division) is not eligible for pay-
ment of its current claims for about AUD$4.4
million in public funding, because it failed to
disclose the identity of all major political donors
in its 2011 declaration. Oral and documentary
evidence from Liberal Party officials and agents
from the Free Enterprise Foundation provided
to ICAC in the course of its Operation Spicer
Inquiry led the Electoral Commission to con
-
clude that there were significant breaches of
election funding laws.
Whether or not there are findings of corrup-
tion followed by prosecutions of individuals, it
cannot sensibly be said that the efforts of the
ICAC have come to naught. Nor is that a justifi-
able conclusion in Ireland. Ireland’s Criminal
Assets Bureau has clawed back millions of
euros from corrupt individuals and tenaciously
continues to do so. In NSW the Criminal Assets
Recovery Act 1990 allows for the same form of
redress.
Law reform is another key outcome. The Plan-
ning Tribunal drew attention to the inadequacies
of Irish law in relation to official corruption. The
Criminal Justice (Corruption) Bill now in its final
stages in Ireland gives effect to some of the Tri-
bunal’s recommendations, and to several
international agreements relating to
corruption.
If all else fails, the levying of hefty tax bills
and prosecution for tax evasion is an outcome
that should not be sniffed at. It was, after all,
tax offences that finally brought down the
seemingly untouchable American gangster Al
Capone.
K
losterman (1985) suggests that the “great
debate” of the 1930s and 1940s between pro-
ponents of government planning and
defenders of free markets and laissez-faire has
never really ended:
Contemporary arguments for abandoning plan-
ning, reducing regulation, and restricting the size
of government are generally accompanied by calls
for increased reliance on private entrepreneurship
and the competitive forces of the market. That is, it
is often argued, government regulation and plan-
ning are unnecessary and often harmful because
they stifle entrepreneurial initiative, impede inno-
vation, and impose unnecessary financial and
administrative burdens on the economy.
Challenges to the legitimacy of the planning
system have intensified in the neoliberal era in
which we still live. A recent example is the nomina-
tion of planning and zoning rules as one of three
priority areas for review, in a review of competition
policy in Australia. The Harper Report argues that:
Planning systems by their nature create barriers
to entry, diversification or expansion, including
through limiting the number, size, operating model
and mix of businesses. This can reduce the respon-
siveness of suppliers to the needs of consumers.
A 2015 article in the Economist complains that:
London has strict rules preventing new struc-
tures blocking certain views of St Paul’s Cathedral.
Google’s plans to build housing on its Mountain
View campus in Silicon Valley are being resisted on
the ground that residents might keep pets, which
could harm the local owl population. Nimbyish resi-
dents of low-density districts can exploit planning
rules on everything from light levels to parking
spaces to block plans for construction.
The Economist sees an association between
planning controls and higher house prices, arguing
‘many households are priced out of more vibrant
places. It is no coincidence that the home-owner-
ship rate in the metropolitan area of downtrodden
Detroit, at 71%, is well above the 55% in booming
San Francisco.’ The article contains the claim that:
… lifting all the barriers to urban growth in Amer-
ica could raise the country’s GDP by between 6.5%
and 13.5%.
In Ireland, influential economist Colm McCarthy
often argues that corruption of the planning pro-
cess is rooted in Ireland's anti-market fundaments:
“Restrictive planning rules, which make planning
permission scarce, are an ingredient in the corrupt-
ing of politics all over the world” (Sunday
Independent, 2012).
Such views have been institutionalised too. For
example, in his evidence in June to the Banking
Inquiry the former chief economist of the Central
Bank, Tom O’Connell, submitted that: “the demand
mania for property took off against the background
of restrictive zoning which limited the supply of
housing: the inevitable result was huge property
price inflation”.
On the other hand, the diagnoses and the pre-
scriptions of neoliberal ideology are not universally
accepted. There is strong public support for the reg-
ulation of development, for a variety of social,
environmental, amenity and financial reasons. An
attempt to add to the changes made to the NSW
biodiversity offset scheme late in 2014 ‘the oppor-
tunity to reduce the value of the required offset if a
project’s social or economic benefit is deemed sig-
nificant enough’ was also fiercely opposed and
eventually abandoned by the NSW State
government.
Opinions will differ on whether or not it is appro-
priate to insist that planning regulations should
work in the interests of “consumers”. Some might
see themselves as citizens living in a society, not
consumers living in a marketplace. Different per-
spectives and ideologies will produce different
views of what constitutes “the public interest”.
So, while the Economist might have a problem
with planning controls protecting views of St Paul’s
Cathedral, Londoners and visitors might well
regard views of Wren’s masterpiece as, literally,
priceless. The Economist (2015) itself anticipates
(and rejects) the retort: ‘give economists their way,
and they would quickly pave over Central Park’.
Julie Walton BA LLB, MTCP, is qualified both as a lawyer and as an urban planner (MTCP). She served as a City of Sydney
Councillor from 1991 to 1999 and was a Principal Officer at the Independent Commission Against Corruption, working in the
Corruption Prevention Division. She is the University of Sydney's Henry Halloran Trust's practitioner in residence.
Conclusion
RECOMMENDATION Prohibit political donations from the property development indus-
try, at all levels of government.
RECOMMENDATION Prohibit political donations from political lobbyists, and bar lobby-
ists from official positions in political parties.
RECOMMENDATION Introduce a presumption of corruption along the lines of that contained
in the Irish Criminal Justice (Corruption) Bill: covering undeclared donations, exceeding allow-
able limits, by a donor who had or has an interest in the recipient “doing any act or making
any omission in relation to his or her office, employment, position or business”.
RECOMMENDATION Confine override provisions in planning systems to the variation of
means, rather than ends. In NSW, this entails removing clause 4.6 (3) (b) from the Standard
Instrument and requiring applicants to demonstrate consistency with objectives, in line with
the assessment required by clause 4.6 (4) (ii).
RECOMMENDATION Developing and drafting clear and robust objectives that function
well when tested by override provisions should form part of the training of every planner.
POLITICS